Thursday 3 December 2015

Gift Cards and the Illiquidity Discount - A Valuation Perspective

With the busiest season of the year for retail sales upon us, you are no doubt wondering what to buy for that special someone. If you’re reading this blog – and I have every reason to believe you are – then what you really want to know is what a Chartered Business Valuator has to say about gift giving. In this post I look at gift giving – and in particular, the silly practice of giving gift cards - from a business valuation perspective.

The Discount for Illiquidity and Jerry Seinfeld
Let us forget about gifts for a moment and think about equity valuation.

Suppose you had the ability to acquire one of two securities. Both securities are in companies that are exactly the same in every way (Company A and Company B) – they are in the same line of business, have the same assets and liabilities, and earn the same amount of income each year. Each company will pay the holder of the security $1,000 per year into perpetuity. The only difference between the two investments is that the holder of the shares of Company B is restricted from selling them for 2 years, while the holder of the shares of Company A has no such restrictions.
Clearly, you would rather own the shares of Company A than Company B, since those of Company A are identical to those of Company B, only they carry no restrictions. Precisely how much more you would pay for the more “liquid” shares of Company A has been a matter of debate within the valuation profession for a number of years, and I have written a lengthy article on the subject (here). In brief, the main sources of data on this discount are so-called “restricted stock” studies.  These studies look at the price at which “restricted stock” is issued in private placements to accredited investors, relative to the current market price of that stock on the public exchanges. For example, if shares of a public company trade at $100 per share, and restricted stock are sold at $80 per share, then the illiquidity discount is $20, or 20%.

How useful are restricted stock studies? One analysis questions their validity. It shows[1] that the firms that issue restricted stock in private placements tend to be predominantly small firms listed “over-the-counter”. It concludes that much of the “discount” observed on these private placements is due to:

·     The relatively poor financial position of the issuing company, and hence its poor bargaining position when it comes to issuing new equity; and,

·     The fact that the observed market price for unrestricted shares of these companies (against which the restricted stock discount is calculated) is itself unrepresentative of the fair market value of those shares.

The Discount on Gift Cards

What does all this have to do with gift cards? It is many years since the great contemporary thinker and social critic, Dilbert, noted that gift certificates are “like money, only worse” (https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=OCvR9_W9osw). Like money, they can be used to purchase goods and services; but unlike money, they can only be used to make purchases from the issuing business. Gift cards are illiquid; they are in many ways like restricted stock. If you recognize the value of liquidity, you will agree with Jerry Seinfeld that cash makes the perfect gift: (https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=aQlhrrqTQmU). Elaine’s reaction betrays a basic unawareness of valuation theory.

So what is the discount for illiquidity on gift cards? How much would you be willing to sell a $100 gift certificate for? It will probably depend on a number of factors:

·         If the card is for a store at which you regularly shop, you may not be willing to sell it for much less than $100.

·         If the card is for a store at which you are likely to shop, but only irregularly, then you may be willing to accept a larger discount, in particular if you are short on cash.

o   For example, I buy my groceries at No Frills and my shoes at the Shoe Company. But I buy groceries every week, and shoes (very) infrequently.  I would not sell a No Frills gift card for less than face value, since I can redeem the full face value in a very short period of time. But I would be glad to get rid of a Shoe Company gift card, which I may not use for a few years, for more of a discount. And if I needed to make a big purchase and was short of funds, I would be willing to take an ever steeper discount.

·         If the card is for a large chain, it will require a smaller discount than a card for a small, speciality store.

o   Cards for large chains are easy to use. Even if the seller does not regularly shop at the chain, many others do, and the card should be easier to unload.

In order to see this phenomenon in effect, you can look at some of the websites that buy and sell gift cards. At www.giftrescue.com, gift cards for gasoline sell at a discount of 3%, while cards for more specialized consumer goods such as clothing can be had for discounts of 35% to 40%. On http://www.cardswap.ca/buy/list, it is grocery gift cards that trade closest to their face value. 
How is this relevant for equity valuations? It suggests that the value of liquidity is investor-specific. The discount given by firms issuing illiquid stock will depend on how badly they need immediate cash. And the illiquidity discount that a purchaser or owner of that stock might apply in valuing it will depend on how much they require liquidity.

Conclusion

So how valuable is liquidity? The short answer is that, with investments as with gift cards: it depends.



[1] Robert Comment, “Revisiting the Illiquidity Discount for Private Companies: A New (and “Skeptical”) Restricted Stock Study”, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 24:1 (Winter 2012);

Monday 9 November 2015

The Patented Medicine (Notice of Compliance) Regulations and The Statute of Monopolies

Do generic drug companies have access to alternative remedies after having been held off the market as a result of a Prohibition Order under section 6 of the Patented Medicine (Notice of Compliance) Regulations? Or is their compensation restricted to the damages scheme outlined in section 8 of the Regulations? In this post, we look at a novel[1] effort on the part of Apotex (Apotex Inc. v Eli Lilly and Company et al, 2015 ONSC 5396) to use an antiquated piece of legislation to do precisely this.

Facts

In 2001, Lilly obtained a patent for the use of a drug called atomoxetine in the treatment of ADHD. Apotex developed its own version of the drug, and would have received its Notice of Compliance to begin selling the drug in late 2008. Lilly filed for, and received, an automatic Prohibition Order under s. 6 of the Regulations that prevented Apotex from selling its atomoxetine until late 2010, when Lilly’s patent was declared invalid.

Apotex pleaded a series of overlapping, alternative claims. It made a claim for damages under section 8 of the Regulations. It also made a claim for unjust enrichment, seeking to disgorge Lilly’s profits while it held its market monopoly. Interestingly, it also brought a claim for treble damages and double costs under the British Statute of Monopolies of 1624 (as well as its more recent Ontario counterpart of 1897). The decision in question concerns the disposition of Lilly’s motion to strike this last part of Apotex’s pleadings.

In rejecting Lilly’s motion, Justice Dunphy noted that Lilly’s “complete code” argument - that the Regulations are a complete code that precludes other sources of financial remedy to the plaintiff generic following the removal of the statutory stay - has not been conclusively determined to apply to the Regulations by any appellate court.  For this reason, he ruled that the arcane statutory cause of action put forth by the plaintiff ought not to be dismissed on a preliminary motion, but instead allowed to proceed to trial where they can be determined on a full factual record. 

It should be noted, of course, that causes of action will only be struck on preliminary motion where it is “plain and obvious” that the cause of action stands no chance of success; therefore, little more can be said at this point about the ultimate merits of the case on these statutes. It may well prove that Apotex’s antiquarian claim receives little more traction than attempts by litigants to obtain a “trial by combat”.

Analysis
Why is it that Apotex has put forth such a creative pleading? It would appear to be a function of Apotex’s continuing efforts to – from its perspective – level the playing field when it comes to the automatic injunctive relief provided by the Regulations.

Under the section 8 damages regime of the Regulations – it has been argued - there is a built-in incentive for the “first persons” or brands to take advantage of the automatic statutory stay provisions of the Regulations, regardless of the merits of the particular patents that it has listed on the patent register. Why is this? Consider that a sale that a generic company was precluded from making during the Relevant Period – i.e. a lost sale for which the brand will pay damages - is a sale that was, in the “real world”, made by the branded drug company. The sole differences are that:

   In the real world, the brand will have made that sale at its brand price, which is set in a monopolistic world.  In the notional “but for” world, the generic drug company (Apotex in this case) is assumed to make many of those same sales, but for only a fraction of the price. For example, during the relevant period for the atomoxetine case (i.e. 2008 to 2010), generic prices in Ontario were equal to roughly 50% of brand prices.

    The level of rebates or customer acquisition costs for branded drugs in a monopolistic world will be negligible. By contrast, the assumed cost of customer acquisition in the “but for” world is quite high, particular when multiple generic entrants are assumed.

As a result, the actual profits per unit made by the brand during the statutory stay period will likely greatly exceed the hypothetical profits that the generic would have made during the time it was kept off the market.  For example, if a brand company sold a drug for $1.00 per tablet in the real world and its variable costs were $0.10 per tablet (for a gross margin of $0.90), and was later found to have wrongly kept a generic off the market, it will pay as little as $0.20 per tablet in damages to the generic to compensate the generic for its losses; the net gain to the brand in such a case will be $0.70 per tablet, no matter the merits of its patent.[2]  Generic drug prices (as a percentage of brands) have continued to drop in recent years; as a result, this gap has continued to widen.
It is this discrepancy between the actual profits of the brand and the potential damages award available to the generics under section 8 that has given rise to Apotex’s (unsuccessful) attempts to recover an award for unjust enrichment (Apotex Inc. v. Eli Lilly Canada Inc., 2011 FCA 358, Apotex Inc v Abbott Laboratories Ltd, 2013 ONCA 555; Apotex Inc v Eli Lilly & Co, 2015 ONCA 305.) The claim for treble damages on the Monopolies Act is simply another attempt to break-out of the “complete code” that the Regulations have been characterized by some courts as being.
Conclusions

Is Apotex likely to recover treble damages? It is probably pointless to predict at this point. As to the broader question of whether the damages component of the Regulations, combined with the automatic right of a brand to injunctive relief, has created an uneven playing field – I am not so sure. Following the Supreme Court’s dismissal of the appeal in Sanofi-Aventis v. Apotex Inc., 2015 SCC 20, there does exist the spectre that, at least in cases involving drugs with multiple generic companies attempting to enter, brands may indeed be left with net losses as a result of multiple, overlapping damages awards or settlements.



[1] Novel for most litigants, anyway; Apotex has played this card several times before. E.g., see Apotex Inc. v. Warner-Lambert Company LLC, 2012 FCA 323
[2] This calculation assumes that the variable costs of producing and selling the medications are similar between the brand and the generics, which is typically the case. The calculation is based on the following assumptions:
 
$1.000 x 50% (formulary standard) x (1-40% rebate) - $0.10 (other variable costs) = $0.20
 

Monday 27 July 2015

Foreign Exchange Issues in Damage Quantification: Part II - Applying the Concepts

In the previous post, we presented a basic framework for analyzing the impact of foreign exchange fluctuations on quantifying financial remedies. We argued that the treatment of foreign exchange should be consistent with the principal underlying the financial remedy being awarded; we referred to this as a "matching principle".

In this post, we extend that basic logic to consider other scenarios.
 
1.     What if we are not sure how to match?

Consider Mr. Canuck, an executive working for a Canadian subsidiary of a US-based public company is wrongfully terminated. As a result, the stock options to which he would have been entitled as of July 2009 did not vest. He sues for wrongful dismissal, and is successful. His damages are assessed as the difference between the exercise price ($1 USD per share) of the options and the market value of the stock on July 2009 ($10 USD per share). The trial occurs in 2011, and an award for damages is granted shortly thereafter.

Arguably, the appropriate exchange rate will depend on particular findings of fact:

 ·         Assume that the court determines damages based on the profit that could have been earned by exercising the options on the date they vested, and immediately selling the shares thus acquired and converting the proceeds into Canadian dollars (to buy a new sportscar). Under this set of assumptions, the relevant exchange rate is the rate in effect on the vesting date, since that is the date Mr. Canuck would have converted his $USD-denominated assets into $CDN. Converting his award based on the current exchange rate will not provide Mr. Canuck with sufficient funds to buy his sportscar![1]
 
·         Conversely, supposing that Mr. Canuck held a large $USD-denominated stock portfolio at the time he would have exercised his options. In that case, it may be more appropriate to assume that he would have simply rolled his company stock into another US investment, which he would have continued to hold. If so, then his damages award should be based on the exchange rate in effect at the award date; Mr. Canuck can take his award, convert it into USD and purchase the same portfolio of stock that he would have purchased following the exercise of his options.

2.     Future Losses

Let us now turn to the example of a personal injury claimant, Ms. Nascar. She is a US resident, and is injured in a motor vehicle accident in Canada, and will never be able to work again. What sort of foreign exchange rate should be applied to her prospective losses?

But for her injuries, Ms. Nascar would have continued to work in the US, earning USD. Her lump sum damages award will be calculated in USD; she will then need to be given a CDN amount such that she will be able to use it to purchase a USD stream of income (e.g. a portfolio of US government bonds) sufficient to replace her lost income. This will be accomplished by looking to the current exchange rate on the award date.

(Some may argue that if the exchange rate on the award date is unusually high or low, it may be fairer to apply some sort of long term forecast exchange rate. I would argue that generally speaking, actual exchange rates are the best reflection of anticipated future rates; to the extent that they are not, the defendant can always enter into a hedging arrangement.

Suppose the liability insurer of the defendant feels that the exchange rate of $1 USD = $1.25 CDN is abnormally high, and that a “fairer” exchange rate to use would be $1 USD = $1.10 CDN. The insurance company could simply borrow USD now, exchange the USD for CDN at the “favourable” exchange rate, and then pay back the USD when the exchange rate “normalizes” to $1 USD = $1.10 CD.)

3.     Damages and Profits

Consider the case of Maple Leaf Technologies Inc. (“MLT”), a Canadian firm who infringes a patent by manufacturing goods in Canada and selling them in the United States. Most of the MLT's operations are in Canada.
 
Under Canadian law, the patent owner – a US based firm, Stripes and Stars Inc. (“SSI”) - may sue for either damages on its lost sales, or an accounting of the defendant’s profits from the infringing sales. I would argue that the appropriate exchange rate to use may depend on the type of financial remedy that is being pursued. 

In an award for damages, the goal is to return the plaintiff to the position it would have been in had the wrongdoing not occurred. The analysis centres on the plaintiff. In the case of the SSI, whose patent was infringed, arguably the treatment of the damages award should depend on what it would have done with its USD sales. Since SSI’s operations are all US-based, the damages award needs to be such that SSI can take the award (based on the exchange rate in effect on the award date) and convert it into USD.[2]

The analysis in an accounting of profits case is different. The focus is on the profit taken by the infringer, which in this case is a Canadian company, MLT. MLT is in the practice of converting the proceeds of its USD sales into CDN, since virtually all of its operations are carried out in the Canada. In order to eliminate the benefit received by MLT from its wrongful sales, it would be more appropriate to quantify the profits to be disgorged based on the actual historic rate at which Maple Leaf Technologies had converted its USD sales into CDN, and not on the rate in effect on the award date.

If this analysis is correct, then fluctuations in foreign exchange rates may be a relevant factor for SSI in deciding which remedy to pursue. Assuming that SSI's lost profits and MLT's incremental profits from the infringing sales are very similar (i.e. that any sales MLT made would have been made by SSI, and the two companies have similar cost structures), and the value of the Canadian dollar has depreciated relative to USD by 20%, then SSI will be better off electing damages.

4.     Hedging

Finally, consider a Canadian firm, Stick and Puck Ltd. ("SPL"), which was unable to make sales to the US as a result of its contractor’s negligence. SPL does a steady volume of business in the US, and in order to reduce its exposure to fluctuations in foreign exchange rates, it typically enters into forward contracts to sell USD and purchase CDN. How does one treat the hedging arrangements that Stick and Puck had entered into? Do they matter?

There are many types of such arrangements, but two common ones which we will consider here are:

·    Forward contracts: These contacts obligate the Canadian firm to exchange a certain amount of USD at a certain date at a certain price.

·    Option contracts: These contracts give the Canadian firm the right (but not the obligation) to exchange a certain amount of USD at a certain date at a certain price.

Let us suppose that SPL lost $1M (USD) in sales as a result of the incident. At the time, the spot exchange rate was $1USD = $1.2CDN, but SPL had entered into a forward contract a number of months prior to that, according to which it agreed to trade $1M USD to its counterparty in exchange for $1.15M CDN.

At first glance, one might think that the relevant exchange rate to apply would be the forward contract rate of $1USD = $1.15CDN, on the grounds that, but for the incident, SPL would have taken its $1M (USD) and exchanged it for $1.15M CDN.

This is not correct, however. A forward contract has an intrinsic value of its own, regardless of whether it is being used to hedge against exchange rate risk or for purely speculative purposes. A contract that requires me to sell $1M (USD) for $1.15M (CDN) when the spot exchange rate is in fact 1 (USD):1.2 (CDN) has a value of negative $0.05M to me, and that needs to be considered. In reality, one should really think of there as being two separate transactions that would have occurred:

 1.     Receive sales proceeds of $1M (USD), convert to $1.2M (CDN) at spot rate.

2.     Take $1.2M (CDN), convert it to $1M (USD), and give the $1M (USD) to the counterparty in exchange for $1.15M (CDN).

Had SPL been able to complete both transactions, its net result would have been to have $1.15M (CDN) in its pocket. However, because it was not able to make the sale for $1M (USD) (Transaction #1), it is left with a loss of $0.05M as a result of the forward contract (Transaction #2). Combining the sales proceeds of $1.15M (CDN) that SPL would have had with the negative $0.05M that they now are stuck with, the aggregate loss is $1.2M.

In short, even if a company enters into forward contracts, the relevant exchange rate will be the spot rate at the time the lost sales would have occurred, not the forward contract rate.

What if SPL had the right, but not the obligation, to sell $1M (USD) in exchange for $1.15M (CDN)? In our example, such an option would have a negative intrinsic value (since the spot rate is $1USD=$1.2CDN); SPL would not have exercised the option, but would have simply exchanged its $1M (USD) received from the sale of its goods based on the spot rate. Again, it is the spot rate that is relevant, not the contracted rate.

Conclusion

Foreign exchange rates can add complexity to financial loss calculations. My central argument in this post has been that the choice of exchange rate should never be a mechanical exercise; rather, it should be a function of how best to achieve the underlying goal of the financial remedy in question. Carrying this line of thinking through to its logical conclusion can yield interesting results.

 

[1] This was essentially the approach adopted by the trial judge in Bailey v. Cintas Corporation, 2008 CanLII 12704 (ON SC),

Friday 24 July 2015

Foreign Exchange Issues in Damage Quantification: Part I - Basic Concepts

International trade is an increasingly important part of the Canadian economy, as this picture clearly shows:
 
 
As a result, it is not uncommon for litigation to involve the quantification of financial remedies across multiple political and monetary boundaries. How does one take foreign exchange rates – and more specifically, fluctuations in foreign exchange rates between the date of initial wrongdoing and the trial date – into account? In the next two posts, I will consider the following five examples, through which I hope to illustrate some basic concepts:

1.   A US-based company, Manifest Destiny Inc. (“MDI”) has a contract to sell $1M (USD) of specialized goods to a Canadian firm. The Canadian firm breaches the contract, and MDI is unable to make the sale (or to mitigate its loss). The exchange rate at the time of breach was $1 USD = $1.25 CDN; it is now $1 USD = $1 CDN.

2.   Gordon C. Canuck (“Mr. Canuck”), an executive working for a Canadian subsidiary of a US-based public company is wrongfully terminated. As a result, the stock options to which he would have been entitled as of July 2009 did not vest. He sues for wrongful dismissal, and is successful. His damages are assessed as the difference between the exercise price ($1 USD per share) of the options and the market value of the stock on July 2009 ($10 USD per share). The trial occurs in 2011, and an award for damages is granted shortly thereafter.

3.   Nancy Nascar, (“Ms. Nascar”) a US resident, is injured in a motor vehicle accident in Canada, and will never be able to work again. She sues the motorist who collided with her, and seeks to recover her future loss of income.

4.   Maple Leaf Technologies Inc. (“MLT”) infringes a patent by manufacturing goods in Canada and selling them in the United States. Most of the firm’s operations are in Canada. Under Canadian law, the patent owner – a US based firm, Stripes and Stars Inc. (“SSI”) - may sue for either damages on its lost sales, or an accounting of the defendant’s profits from the infringing sales.

5.   Stick and Puck Ltd. (“SPL”) a Canadian firm that manufactures products in Canada and sells them in the United States, suffers a fire in its factory. It sues the electrical contractor to recover its lost profits. SPL does a steady volume of business in the US, and in order to reduce its exposure to fluctuations in foreign exchange rates, it typically enters into forward contracts to sell USD and purchase CDN.

 The Law

You may be asking at this point, why not simply quantify whatever the financial remedy is in the foreign currency? If only it were that simple!The Currency Act, R.S.C., 1985, c. C-52, s. 12, requires that any money referenced in a legal proceeding in Canada must be stated in Canadian currency.  It is on this basis that Canadian courts have generally felt compelled to convert awards for financial loss into Canadian dollars, even if the losses relate to a foreign currency.

There was, for many years, an established rule that the exchange rate be set based on the date of breach or wrongdoing. As summarized by the Manitoba Court of Appeal:

 
89                    At present, the Canadian “breach date rule” is based on a series of Canadian cases which adopted a now obsolete British rule.

90                        In 1945, the Supreme Court of Canada, in Gatineau Power Co. v. Crown Life Insurance Co., 1945 CanLII 33 (SCC), [1945] S.C.R. 655, applied a date of conversion at breach date in an action to recover a debt.  They did so in brief reasons, referring to the cases of The Custodian v. Blucher, 1927 CanLII 69 (SCC), [1927] S.C.R. 420 (a case dealing with unpaid dividends), and S.S. Celia v. S.S. Volturno, [1921] 2 A.C. 544 (H.L.).

91                        Those two cases, in turn, relied upon principles enunciated by previous English House of Lords cases.  That principle was that in all cases involving sums payable in a foreign currency, the applicable rate of exchange was the rate in existence on the date of breach.  See, for example, Re United Railways of the Havana and Regla Warehouses, Ltd., [1960] 2 All E.R. 332 (H.L.).[1]

The MBCA went on to describe how some Canadian jurisdictions have moved away from this principle, writing into their statutes specific rules to the contrary. For example, in Ontario, section 121 of the Courts of Justice Act stipulates that a damages award calculated in a foreign currency must be converted to Canadian dollars based on the exchange rate in effect at the judgment date; section 121(3) of that Act provides the court with discretion to use an alternate exchange rate when warranted. Other jurisdictions, even without explicit statutory adjustments, have also departed from this "rule" (as indeed did the MBCA in the case in question).

In this post and the next, I will discuss a variety of situations in which the issue of foreign currency conversion will arise. I will suggest that a simple set of principles can be applied to cut through some of the confusion to arrive at monetary awards that are economically fair and predictable.

1.     Matching the Remedy to the Loss

The basic principle behind an award for damages is to return the injured party to the position he or she would have been in but for the wrongdoing. Let us apply this principle to the question of foreign exchange in each of the five examples listed above.

Turning to our first example listed above, consider that MDI is a US company, and its lost sales were in USD. The exchange rate at the date of breach is irrelevant to MDI; MDI was never going to take the proceeds from the sale and invest them in Canadian dollars. It would have taken the USD from the sale and used them to run its US-based business. It has lost USD.

In order to be made whole, MDI needs to receive an amount of Canadian dollars such that it can take them to the bank today and convert them into $1M USD (the amount of its loss). The relevant exchange rate is therefore the rate in effect on the award date, not on the date of breach.

(By the same logic, if there is a delay between the award date and the date of actual payment, we would argue that it is the date of actual payment that is more relevant.)[2]

Conclusion
 
Thus far, I have argued that the treatment of foreign exchange should be consistent with the principal underlying the financial remedy being awarded. In the next post, I will show how this approach can be applied to other types of cases.



[1] Kellogg Brown & Root Inc. v. Aerotech Herman Nelson Inc. et al, 2004 MBCA 63, at para. 89. This decision contains a useful summary of the legal background to this issue.
[2] This is an issue that the MBCA grappled with in Kellogg.
 

Wednesday 22 July 2015

The Dividend Double Count

In this post, I touch on a common error I encounter in dealing with a financial analysis of multiple companies owned by the same group or individual. I call this error the “dividend double count”, for reasons that will become apparent momentarily. The error arises in various areas of my practice, but most commonly in the areas of family law and personal injury.

The Issue
The error is as follows. Consider the following simple ownership structure:

Now, suppose that during the most recent calendar year, the following results were reported:
 
 
The question that arises in a family law context is: what was the pre-tax income available to Mr. Shareholder? An intuitive response might be to simply look at the “income before taxes” line on the income statements of Opco and Holdco, and take the sum of $120,000 (i.e. $80,000 + $40,000). Some may also be tempted to pick up the $15,000 in dividends paid to Mr. Shareholder.
But this would be wrong.
Opco shows dividends paid of $45,000. Holdco is the sole shareholder of Opco, so those dividends – which have not been deducted in calculating Opco’s income before taxes – are appearing as part of Holdco’s revenue (along with some miscellaneous revenue).

Had Opco paid out a $45,000 management fee to Holdco, the analysis would be much simpler; the management fee would show as an expense to Opco and as revenue to Holdco; the impact on the combined net income of the two companies would be neutral. The problem really arises because dividends are not deducted in calculating income. In order to calculate the overall pre-tax income, it is necessary to deduct the $45,000 in intercompany dividends. The actual pre-tax income of the two corporations is $120,000 - $45,000 =  $75,000.
(The same commentary would apply to the $15,000 reported by Mr. Shareholder on his personal tax return; these have been paid out of Holdco’s pre-tax income, and should not be included again at the personal level in analyzing Mr. Shareholder’s income).
Other Contexts

This issue also arises in other situations. A number of years ago I analyzed the income of a group of real estate development companies in the context of a claim for personal injury damages. The plaintiff’s expert had presented a claim based on a decline in net income between the pre-accident and post-accident periods, but had neglected to consider the distortions created by the issuance of large intercompany dividends.

Conclusion

Dividends issued from one company to another are included in the income of the recipient, but are not deducted from the income of the issuer.[1] In analysing the revenue or profitability of a group of companies, it is important to gain an understanding of how the revenue of each company is generated in order to gain a proper picture and to avoid double counting.



[1] The Income Tax Act recognizes this; intercompany dividends amongst related companies are not subject to tax in the hands of the recipient company.