The Concept
The concept behind springboard profits is that, by virtue of
having infringed a patent, the infringer has achieved a financial advantage
that continues beyond the expiry of the patent. This can occur for several
reasons:
- A valid patent prohibits not only the sale, but also the manufacture and offering for sale of an invention covered by the patent. This means that had the infringer not infringed during the life of the patent, it would have taken some time to develop its product, to build up inventory, to market the product and build distribution channels. In short, it would have taken months, if not years, to build up their sales to a steady plateau. By infringing, the infringer is able to “hit the ground running” following the expiry of the patent.
- If the patented product is a durable good, then the benefits to the infringer in selling that good may include not only the initial sale, but also the sale of replacement parts, maintenance services, or other associated revenue streams. While the initial sale of the good may have taken place during the life of the patent, there will be additional benefits accruing to the infringer well beyond the life of the patent.
-
In some instances, there may be an even
longer-lasting benefit to the infringer. The existence of multiple firms
already selling the patented product by the time of the patent’s expiry may
dissuade additional firms from joining the market following the patent’s
expiry, firms who may otherwise have entered the market if there had been only
a single incumbent with whom to compete. In situations like this, the
infringer’s benefit will continue into the indefinite future.
Nova’s Argument
While they were ultimately rejected,
the arguments raised by Nova also deserve some comment. Nova advanced several
arguments. Conceptually, the most interesting arguments was the following:- An infringer who disgorges its profits from infringement is implicitly acting as the agent of the patentee, and such payments implicitly serve to effectively condone the infringing activities themselves.
- The difficulty with this argument is that the
profits remedy is not necessarily equal to the amount that, in the real
world, the plaintiff would have agreed to in exchange for use of its patented
technology. In many cases (such as the Dow case) the plaintiff would clearly
never have agreed to license the technology under those terms, as its Minimum
Willingness to Accept would be based on the damages it would suffer by reason
of losing its monopoly over the invention in question.
Could Nova’s argument
work in a damages context?
Is there a situation in which Nova’s argument would have
carried more weight? Perhaps.
Suppose a plaintiff elects a damages remedy, which it
measures based on a reasonable royalty since it is unable to prove it suffered
any loss of sales as a result of the infringement. In that scenario, the plaintiff’s MWTA is
less than the defendant’s MWTP; that is, the benefit to the defendant from
licensing is greater than the value to the plaintiff of its monopoly. This
arises most commonly where the plaintiff is a smaller firm, while the defendant
is much larger and able to scale to market.
In that case, a hypothetical royalty rate (and a fortiori an empirically based royalty
rate, measured based on comparable transactions) should incorporate the fact
that the defendant will thereby gain a springboard advantage. If so, then there
should be no award of springboard damages.
This conclusion is implicit in the words of Justice
Fothergill at paragraph 123 of the Dow decision:
[123] Dow is entitled to awards under
both ss 55(1) and 55(2) of the Patent Act.
Even if the royalty rates calculated by Dr. Heeb and Dr. Leonard can be said to
include the period following the expiration of the ’705 Patent, the royalty
compensates Dow only for Nova’s infringement during the period December 9, 2004
to August 21, 2006. The accounting of profits extends over a much longer
period.
No comments:
Post a Comment